proiect de tradus

Upload: andra-leitoiu

Post on 05-Apr-2018

254 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    1/38

    Risk Management with Stress Testing: Implications for

    Portfolio Selection and Asset Pricing

    Gordon J. Alexander

    University of Minnesota

    Alexandre M. Baptista

    The George Washington University

    June 22, 2006

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    2/38

    Risk Management with Stress Testing: Implications for

    Portfolio Selection and Asset Pricing

    Abstract

    Stress Testing (ST) is often used by banks and securities firms to set risk exposure

    limits. Accordingly, we examine a model with an agent who faces K binding ST constraints

    and another who does not. We obtain four results. First, the constrained agents optimal

    portfolio exhibits (K+2)-fund separation. Second, the effect of the constraints on the optimal

    portfolio is identical to that of an adjustment in the expected returns of the risky securities

    that tends to lower them, thereby increasing the optimal portfolios weight in the riskfree

    security (or the minimum variance portfolio when this security is not available). Third, the

    market portfolio is inefficient. Fourth, a securitys expected return is affected by both its

    systematic risk and its idiosyncratic returns in the states used in the constraints. Thus, we

    provide further motivation to the literature in which security prices are not solely driven bysystematic risk.

    JEL classification: G11; G12; D81

    Keywords: Stress Testing; Portfolio Selection; Asset Pricing; Idiosyncratic Returns

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    3/38

    1. INTRODUCTION

    Over the past ten years, some investors have suffered huge losses due to extreme events.

    For example, Barings Bank failed in 1995, Long Term Capital Management (LTCM) collapsed

    in 1998, and Enron went bankrupt in 2001. Furthermore, the terrorist attacks in the U.S.

    (2001), Spain (2004), and the U.K. (2005) have tremendously affected financial markets.

    Since the occurrence of these events, the importance of risk management has been ex-

    tensively recognized by banks and securities firms when deciding the amount of risk they

    are willing to take. Moreover, bank regulators now put an emphasis on risk management

    practices in attempting to reduce the fragility of banking systems.

    Of the risk management tools currently available, Value-at-Risk (VaR) and Stress Testing

    (ST) have emerged as two of the most popular. For example, under the Basle Capital Accord,

    VaR is used in setting the minimum capital requirement associated with a banks exposure

    to market risk. Furthermore, the Committee on the Global Financial System (2005, pp. 1,

    15) of the Bank for International Settlements and Scholes (2000) note that ST is often used

    by banks and securities firms to set risk exposure limits.

    While the previous literature examines the impact of using VaR as a risk management

    tool on portfolio selection and asset pricing (see, e.g., Alexander and Baptista (2002)), it

    has yet to similarly explore the impact of using ST constraints. Our paper fills this gap

    in the literature by providing parsimonious characterizations of (1) optimal portfolios in

    the presence of ST constraints and (2) equilibrium security expected returns in a two-agent

    economy where one agent faces these constraints and the other does not.

    1

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    4/38

    An examination of the impact of ST constraints is of particular interest for several reasons.

    First, as noted earlier, financial institutions often use them to set risk exposure limits. Second,

    even when a financial institution holds capital in excess of the minimum capital requirements

    as determined by the Basle Capital Accord, the ST constraints may still be binding. This

    can happen since ST captures extreme events where losses can be very large. Third, since

    there is empirical evidence that equity returns have skewness and kurtosis (see, e.g., Harvey

    and Siddique (2000) and Dittmar (2002)), an ST constraint is a device that can be utilized to

    control portfolio skewness and kurtosis. Fourth, the use of ST constraints can be motivated

    by the goal of limiting losses arising from the need to unwind positions in markets that

    become illiquid as a result of extreme events such as the LTCM collapse. Finally, since

    the return distributions of portfolios can resemble those of certain options strategies (see,

    e.g., Merton (1981) and Jagannathan and Korajczyk (1986)), the use of ST constraints can

    mitigate the option-like features in these distributions.

    In investigating the impact of ST constraints, we use Markowitzs (1952, 1959) mean-

    variance model. There are important reasons for doing so. First, this model is the corner-

    stone of portfolio theory. Second, it is widely used in practice to (1) determine optimal asset

    allocations, (2) measure gains from international diversification, and (3) evaluate portfolio

    performance. Third, since a set of ST constraints captures some measure of risk beyond vari-

    ance (i.e., the returns in extreme events), a mean-variance objective function is of interest.

    Finally, the model has been extensively used in the banking literature.

    2

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    5/38

    Regardless on whether a riskfree security is available, we obtain four main results. First,

    the constrained agents optimal portfolio exhibits (K + 2)-fund separation, where K is the

    number of binding ST constraints. While this result might not seem to be particularly

    surprising, Alexander and Baptista (2006a) have shown that under certain conditions a

    constrained agents optimal portfolio still exhibits two-fund separation in the presence of

    a binding risk management constraint.

    Second, the effect of the constraints on the optimal portfolio is identical to that of an

    adjustment in the expected returns of all risky securities that tends to lower them. Hence,

    the constraints tend to increase the optimal portfolios weight in the riskfree security (or the

    minimum variance portfolio when this security is not available).

    Third, the market portfolio is inefficient. The reason why this result holds is that only

    two of the K+ 2 funds required for the constrained agents optimal portfolio are efficient.

    Fourth, a securitys expected return is affected by both its systematic risk (i.e., beta)

    and its idiosyncratic returns in each one of those states that are used in the constraints.

    Specifically, securities with negative (positive) idiosyncratic returns in these states have rel-

    atively high (low) expected returns in equilibrium. The intuition for this result is straight-

    forward. Due to the constraints, it is costly (beneficial) for the constrained agent to hold

    securities with negative (positive) idiosyncratic returns in these states. Accordingly, the

    agent requires them to have relatively high (low) expected returns.

    3

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    6/38

    Next, we illustrate our theoretical results with a simple example. In this example, there

    are five securities (one of them is riskfree), two agents (each one has half of the wealth in

    the economy), and two binding ST constraints. Our main findings are as follows. First,

    since there are two constraints, the constrained agents optimal portfolio exhibits four-fund

    separation. Second, the portfolios weights in the two inefficient funds are notable, which

    cause it to have an efficiency loss of 3.79%. Third, since the market portfolios weights in

    these funds are smaller than those of the constrained agents optimal portfolio, the market

    portfolio has an efficiency loss of only 0.63%. Fourth, the effect of the constraints on the

    optimal portfolio is identical to that of a downward adjustment in the expected returns

    of the risky securities ranging from 2.81% to 9.23%. Thus, the weight of the constrained

    agents optimal portfolio in the riskfree security is substantially larger than that of the

    unconstrained agents optimal portfolio. Fifth, the cost of ST as measured by the reduction

    in the certainty equivalent return incurred by selecting the constrained portfolio is 3.16%.

    Finally, the component of a securitys expected return that arises from its idiosyncratic

    returns can be notable. This component is 2.42% for one of the securities that has negative

    idiosyncratic returns in both of the states used in the constraints. However, the component

    is 1.25% for one of the other securities since it has positive idiosyncratic returns in these

    states. In sum, by exploring the implications of ST constraints, we contribute to the literature

    in which security prices are not solely driven by systematic risk.

    Previous theoretical papers in this literature have recognized the importance of idiosyn-

    cratic risk. For example, Levy (1978), Merton (1987), and Malkiel and Xu (2002) develop

    models in which security expected returns depend on both systematic and idiosyncratic risk.

    4

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    7/38

    The empirical literature has also examined the importance of idiosyncratic risk. Campbell,

    Lettau, Malkiel, and Xu (2001) and Malkiel and Xu (2003) show that the risk of individual

    stocks has noticeably increased over time. Goyal and Santa-Clara (2003) provide evidence of

    a significant positive relation between (1) a measure of idiosyncratic risk given by the equal-

    weighted average stock risk and (2) the market return. However, Bali, Cakici, Yan, and

    Zhang (2005) find no evidence of a significant relation between the value-weighted average

    stock risk and the market return. Moreover, Guo and Savickas (2006) show that when the

    value-weighted average stock risk and aggregate stock market risk are jointly used to forecast

    the market return, there is a significant negative relation between the value-weighted average

    stock risk and the market return. Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006a,b) examine the

    cross-sectional relation between the idiosyncratic risk of individual stocks and their returns,

    and find that U.S. and other developed-market stocks with higher idiosyncratic risk earn

    lower average returns.

    Two features of our work differ from the idiosyncratic risk literature. First, the reason

    why idiosyncratic returns affect expected returns in our model (i.e., the ST constraints) is,

    to the best of our knowledge, novel. Second, our model captures the effects of idiosyncratic

    returns in some states (i.e., those used in the ST constraints) on asset pricing while the

    models in the literature capture the effects of idiosyncratic risk on asset pricing. Hence, the

    model is able to generate equilibrium expected returns consistent with the evidence provided

    by Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006a,b) that stocks with high idiosyncratic risk earn

    low average returns. For example, consider a security with (1) high idiosyncratic risk and

    (2) positive idiosyncratic returns in the states used in the ST constraints. Consistent with

    empirical evidence, our model predicts that such a security has a relatively low expected

    5

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    8/38

    return.

    Since our work derives the effects of a certain measure of risk beyond variance on asset

    pricing, it is important to emphasize that there is an extensive literature that examines the

    effects of skewness and kurtosis. In a seminal paper, Kraus and Litzenberger (1976) develop

    a model that captures the effect of unconditional skewness. Lim (1989) tests their model

    using stock returns and provides evidence that skewness is priced. More recently, Harvey and

    Siddique (2000) explore a model where conditional skewness is priced and present empirical

    evidence that it is helpful in explaining the cross-sectional variation in stock returns. Finally,

    Dittmar (2002) develops a framework in which agents are averse to kurtosis.

    Our work differs from this literature in two respects. First, the importance of a measure

    of risk beyond variance arises in our model due to the existence of ST constraints while it

    arises in other models from agents having either a preference for right-skewed portfolios over

    left-skewed portfolios or an aversion to kurtosis. Second, our model captures the effects of

    the returns in just those states used in the ST constraints on asset pricing while other models

    use the returns in all states to capture the effects of skewness and kurtosis.

    Also related to our work are papers that investigate portfolio selection when an agent

    keeps his or her wealth above a floor. For example, Black and Perold (1992) and Grossman

    and Vila (1992) examine the case when the floor is non-stochastic, while Grossman and Zhou

    (1993) and Cvitanic and Karatzas (1995) examine the case when the floor is stochastic. Our

    work differs from these papers in several important ways. First, we examine the impact of a

    set of ST constraints rather than that of a floor. Second, we derive equilibrium results in

    6

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    9/38

    the presence of ST constraints, while the aforementioned papers focus on portfolio selection

    when an agent keeps his or her wealth above a floor. Finally, we use the mean-variance model

    rather than the expected utility maximization continuous-time model.

    The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 characterizes optimal portfolios and equilib-

    rium security expected returns when a riskfree security is present. Section 3 examines the

    case when a riskfree security is absent. Section 4 provides an example that illustrates our

    theoretical results and Section 5 concludes. The Appendix contains the proofs.

    2. THE MODEL

    2.1. Securities

    Consider an economy where uncertainty is represented by S states. There are J risky

    securities and a riskfree security with return R . The returns of the risky securities are given

    by a J S matrix R, with R denoting the return of security j in state s. Let R be the

    J 1 expected return vector and V be the J J variance-covariance matrix associated with

    R. Let R [R R ] . Suppose that (1) there is no arbitrage; (2) rank(V) = J

    so that there are no redundant securities; and (3) rank([1 R R R ]) = J for

    any set ofJ 2 distinct states, s ,...,s , where 1 denotes the J 1 vector [1 1] .

    A portfolio is a (J+ 1) 1 vector w with w = 1 w 1, where w [w w ] .Let R denote the return of portfolio w in state s. Let R and denote, respectively, the

    expected return and variance of w.

    7

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    10/38

    2.2. Agents

    There are two agents with a mean-variance objective function U : R R R defined

    by

    U(R, ) = R

    2 , (1)

    where > 0. The unconstrained agent has = . The constrained agent has = , and

    is restricted to select a portfolio w that satisfies K binding Stress Testing (ST) constraints:

    R T , s = s ,...,s ,

    where (i) 1 K J 2, (ii) s ,...,s are distinct states, and (iii) T ,...,T are possibly

    distinct bounds in states s ,...,s , respectively.

    2.3. Portfolio Selection Implications

    Next, we characterize the optimal portfolios of unconstrained and constrained agents.

    2.3.1. Unconstrained Agent

    A portfolio is on the mean-variance boundary if there is no other portfolio with the same

    expected return and a smaller variance. A portfolio is efficient if it lies on this boundary and

    has an expected return equal to or greater than R . Otherwise, the portfolio is inefficient.

    Let A 1 V R, B R V R, and C 1 V 1. Let w [0 0 1] and

    w 0 denote the riskfree and tangency portfolios. Portfolios w and ware useful to characterize the unconstrained agents optimal portfolio.

    8

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    11/38

    Theorem 1. The unconstrained agents optimal portfolio is

    w = (1 )w + w , (2)

    where .

    Theorem 1 says that the unconstrained agents optimal portfolio w exhibits two-fund

    separation. Since these funds are w and w , w is efficient. Note that if R is smaller

    (larger) than A/C, then w is efficient (inefficient) and is positive (negative). Figure 1

    illustrates Theorem 1 when > 0. Note that w , w , and w , represented by, respectively,

    points f, t, and u, lie on the line representing the efficient frontier.

    2.3.2. Constrained Agent

    Let F 1 V R and w

    0

    where s = s ,...,s . Portfolios

    w , ...,w are useful to characterize the constrained agents optimal portfolio.

    Theorem 2. The constrained agents optimal portfolio is

    w =

    1

    w + w +

    w , (3)

    where , for s = s ,...,s , and ,..., are Lagrange multipliers

    associated with the ST constraints.

    Theorem 2 says that the constrained agents optimal portfolio w exhibits (K+ 2)-fund

    separation. Since these funds are w , w , and w ,...,w where the last K funds are

    inefficient, w is also inefficient.

    Figure 1 illustrates Theorem 2 when K = 1 and < 0. Note that w and w ,

    represented by, respectively, points s and c, lie below the efficient frontier. Using Equation

    9

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    12/38

    (3), we have

    w = (1 )w + w , (4)

    where + and w . Note that w , represented by point x, lies on the

    dashed hyperbola representing combinations of w and w . As Equation (4) implies, w

    lies on the dotted line representing combinations of w and w .

    To isolate the impact of the ST constraints on the optimal portfolio from that of, assume

    that = . Using Theorems 1 and 2, we have = . Thus, the constraints do not affect

    the optimal portfolios weight in fund w . Furthermore, since the fund weights of each of the

    optimal portfolios sum to one, we have = (1 ) 1 . That is,the sum of w s weights in funds w ,...,w is equal to the difference between the weights

    of w and w in fund w .

    The following result further explores the effect of the constraints on the optimal portfolio.

    Theorem 3. Suppose that = . The constrained agents optimal portfolio when the

    expected return vector is R coincides with the unconstrained agents optimal portfolio when

    the expected return is R R +

    (R 1R ).

    Using Theorem 3, the effect of the ST constraints on the optimal portfolio is identical

    to that of an adjustment in the expected return vector R. Since > 0 for s = s ,...,s ,

    security js adjusted expected return R is smaller (larger) than its expected return R if

    R is smaller (larger) than R for s = s ,...,s . In practice, a state is chosen to be in an

    ST constraint only if there are some securities with negative returns in the state. Hence, the

    case when R R for j = 1,...,J and s = s ,...,s is not plausible.

    In the case when R < R for j = 1,...,J and s = s ,...,s , the expected returns

    of all risky securities are adjusted downward. Thus, fund w is relatively more attractive.

    10

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    13/38

    Consequently, the optimal portfolios weight in w tends to be larger in the presence of the

    constraints.

    Consider now the case when R < R < R for some distinct securities j , j

    {1,...,J} and states s, s {s ,...,s }. In this case, (1) the expected return of at least

    one risky security can be adjusted downward and (2) the expected return of at least one

    risky security can be adjusted upward. Thus, fund w can be either relatively more or less

    attractive. Consequently, there is no clear tendency for the optimal portfolios weight in w

    in the presence of the constraints.

    2.4. Asset Pricing Implications

    Letting m R denote the market portfolio and denote the covariance between

    security j and m, security js beta is / . Furthermore, let be the constrained

    agents fraction of the wealth in the economy, where 0 < < 1.

    Theorem 4. In equilibrium, the market portfolio is inefficient. Furthermore, security js

    expected return is

    R = R + (R R )

    [(R R ) (R R )] , (5)

    where

    /

    (1 )/ + /, k = 1,...,K, (6)

    is a positive constant.

    Theorem 4 says that in equilibrium the market portfolio is inefficient. The intuition for

    this result is straightforward. Since (1) the unconstrained agents optimal portfolio is efficient,

    (2) the constrained agents optimal portfolio is inefficient, and (3) the market portfolio is a

    11

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    14/38

    combination of these optimal portfolios, the market portfolio is inefficient. Figure 1 illustrates

    that when K = 1, the market portfolio, represented by point m, lies below the efficient frontier

    on the dashed hyperbola representing combinations of w and w .

    Equation (5) indicates that security js expected return depends on K + 2 terms. The

    first two terms, R and (R R ), are identical to those contained in the CAPM.

    However, the last K terms, which are subtracted from the sum of the first two terms, are not

    present in the CAPM. Each one of these K terms is given by the product of: (1) security js

    idiosyncratic return in state s , (R R ) (R R ), and (2) the risk premium on

    the idiosyncratic return in state s , , where k {1,...,K}. We refer to the sum of these

    K terms as the idiosyncratic return adjustment.

    Since > 0 for k = 1,...,K, whether security js expected return is larger than, equal

    to, or smaller than that in the CAPM depends on its idiosyncratic returns in states s ,...,s .

    First, if security js idiosyncratic return is zero in states s ,...,s , then its expected return

    is equal to that in the CAPM. Second, if security js idiosyncratic return is (1) either zero or

    positive in states s ,...,s , and (2) positive for some state s {s ,...,s }, then its expected

    return is smaller than that in the CAPM. Third, if security js idiosyncratic return is (1)

    either zero or negative in states s ,...,s , and (2) negative for some state s {s ,...,s },

    then its expected return is larger than that in the CAPM. Finally, if security js idiosyncratic

    return is negative in some state s {s ,...,s } and positive in some state s {s ,...,s },

    then its expected return can be smaller than, equal to, or larger than that in the CAPM.

    The intuition for why securities with negative (positive) idiosyncratic returns in states

    s ,...,s have relatively high (low) expected returns in equilibrium is straightforward. Due

    12

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    15/38

    to the constraints, it is costly (beneficial) for the constrained agent to hold securities with

    negative (positive) idiosyncratic returns in these states. Accordingly, the agent requires them

    to have relatively high (low) expected returns.

    Using Equation (6), the risk premium on the idiosyncratic return in state s depends on

    two constants: (1) and (2) . The first constant measures the constrained

    agents marginal cost (in terms of utility) arising from marginally decreasing the bound T

    (i.e., tightening the ST constraint in state s ). The second constant measures the constrained

    agents fraction of the risk-aversion-adjusted wealth in the economy. Note that if = ,

    then this constant is equal to .

    3. ABSENCE OF A RISKFREE SECURITY

    Suppose now that there is no riskfree security. Let w and w denote, re-

    spectively, the minimum variance portfolio and the portfolio on the mean-variance boundary

    with expected return B/A.

    3.1. Portfolio Selection Implications

    Next, we characterize the optimal portfolios of unconstrained and constrained agents.

    3.1.1. Unconstrained Agent

    In the absence of a riskfree security, a portfolio is efficient if it lies on the mean-variance

    boundary and has an expected return equal to or greater than A/C (i.e., that of w ).

    Theorem 5. The unconstrained agents optimal portfolio is

    w = (1 )w + w , (7)

    where .

    Theorem 5 says that the unconstrained agents optimal portfolio w exhibits two-fund

    13

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    16/38

    separation. Since these funds are w and w , w is efficient. Figure 2 illustrates Theorem 5.

    Note that w , w , and w , represented by, respectively, points a, b, and u, lie on the upper

    part of the thick hyperbola representing the mean-variance boundary.

    3.1.2. Constrained Agent

    Let w for s = s ,...,s . Portfolios w ,...,w are useful to characterize the

    constrained agents optimal portfolio.

    Theorem 6. The constrained agents optimal portfolio is

    w = 1 w + w + w , (8)where , for s = s ,...,s , and ,..., are Lagrange multipliers associ-

    ated with the ST constraints.

    Theorem 6 says that the constrained agents optimal portfolio w exhibits (K+ 2)-fund

    separation. Since these funds are w , w , and w ,...,w where the last K funds are

    inefficient, w is also inefficient.

    Figure 2 illustrates Theorem 6 when K = 1 and < 0. Note that w and w ,

    represented by, respectively, points s and c, lie below the efficient frontier. Using Equation

    (8), we have

    w = (1 )w + w , (9)

    where + and w . Note that w , represented by point x, lies on the

    dashed hyperbola representing combinations of w and w . As Equation (9) implies, w

    lies on the dotted hyperbola representing combinations of w and w .

    To isolate the impact of the ST constraints on the optimal portfolio from that of, assume

    that = . Using Theorems 5 and 6, we have = . Thus, the constraints do not affect

    14

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    17/38

    the optimal portfolios weight in fund w . Furthermore, since the fund weights of each of the

    optimal portfolios sum to one, we have

    = (1 )

    1

    . That is,

    the sum of w s weights in funds w ,...,w is equal to the difference between the weights

    of w and w in fund w .

    The following result further explores the effect of the constraints on the optimal portfolio.

    Theorem 7. Suppose that = . The constrained agents optimal portfolio when the

    expected return vector is R coincides with the unconstrained agents optimal portfolio when

    the expected return is R R + R .Using Theorem 7, the effect of the ST constraints on the optimal portfolio is identical

    to that of an adjustment in the expected return vector R. Since > 0 for s = s ,...,s ,

    security js adjusted expected return R is smaller (larger) than its expected return R if

    R is smaller (larger) than zero for s = s ,...,s . Note that the case when R 0 for

    j = 1,...,J and s = s ,...,s is not plausible since in practice a state is chosen to be in an

    ST constraint only if there are some securities with negative returns in the state.

    In the case when R < 0 for j = 1,...,J and s = s ,...,s , the expected returns of

    all risky securities are adjusted downward. Thus, fund w is relatively more attractive.

    Consequently, the optimal portfolios weight in w tends to be larger in the presence of the

    constraints.

    Consider now the case when R < 0 < R for some distinct securities j , j {1,...,J}

    and states s, s {s ,...,s }. In this case, (1) the expected return of at least one security can

    be adjusted downward and (2) the expected return of at least one security can be adjusted

    upward. Thus, fund w can be either relatively more or less attractive. Consequently, there

    is no clear tendency for the optimal portfolios weight in w in the presence of the constraints.

    15

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    18/38

    3.2. Asset Pricing Implications

    We now characterize the equilibrium.

    Theorem 8. In equilibrium, the market portfolio is inefficient. Furthermore, security js

    expected return is

    R = R + (R R) R R , (10)where

    R 1 (1 )A/ A/

    F /

    (1 )/ + / 1

    C(11)

    and is a positive constant as defined in Equation (6).

    Theorem 8 says that the market portfolio is inefficient. The intuition for this result is

    similar to that of Theorem 4. Figure 2 illustrates that the market portfolio, represented by

    point m, lies below the efficient frontier on the thin hyperbola representing combinations of

    wand

    w.

    Equation (10) indicates that security js expected return depends on K+ 2 terms. The

    first two terms are related to those in the Black model. However, the last K terms, which

    are subtracted from the sum of the first two terms, are not present in the Black model. Each

    one of these K terms is given by the product of: (1) the idiosyncratic return of security j

    in state s , R R , and (2) the risk premium on the idiosyncratic return in state s ,

    , where k {1,...,K}.

    16

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    19/38

    Since > 0 for k = 1,...,K, securities with negative (positive) idiosyncratic returns in

    states s ,...,s have relatively high (low) expected returns in equilibrium. The intuition for

    this result is similar to that presented for Theorem 4.

    4. EXAMPLE

    In this section, we illustrate our theoretical results using a simple example.

    4.1. Securities

    There are four risky securities (j = 1, 2, 3, 4) and a riskfree security (j = 5). The risky

    securities are assumed to be in positive net supply, while the riskfree security is assumed

    to be in zero net supply. Panel (a) of Table 1 presents their expected returns and standard

    deviations. For simplicity, assume that the correlation coefficient between the returns of each

    pair of distinct risky securities is equal to 0.4. As explained shortly, the constrained agent

    faces two ST constraints which use states s and s . Panel (b) of Table 1 provides the security

    returns in these states. These returns are notably negative, but nevertheless plausible. For

    example, the Nasdaq index declined by 27.1% and 22.9% in, respectively, October 1987 and

    November 2000. It is important to emphasize that the qualitative results in our example do

    not depend on the assumptions that are imposed on (1) the existence of a riskfree security,

    (2) the net supply of the riskfree security, (3) the distribution of security returns, and (4)

    the number of ST constraints.

    4.2. Agents

    The unconstrained and constrained agents have the objective function defined by Equa-

    17

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    20/38

    tion (1) with = = = 2. The constrained agent faces two ST constraints:

    R T , s = s , s ,

    where T = 3% and T = 4%. The reason why we have T > T is that the returns of

    three out of the four risky securities in state s are larger in absolute terms than those in

    state s . Nevertheless, examples with similar results can be constructed when T T .

    4.3. Portfolio Selection Implications

    Table 2 presents the optimal portfolios of unconstrained and constrained agents.

    4.3.1. Unconstrained Agent

    The first row of panel (a) indicates that the unconstrained agents optimal portfolio w

    is characterized by weights = 36.93% and = 136.93% in, respectively, funds w and

    w . The first row of panel (b) shows that w s weights in the risky securities range from

    28.50% (security 4) to 41.42% (security 1). The first row of panel (d) says that w s expected

    return and standard deviation are, respectively, 16.32% and 25.07%. Moreover, w s returns

    in states s and s , at 21.02% and 25.74%, are notably negative.

    4.3.2. Constrained Agent

    The second row of panel (a) indicates that the constrained agents optimal portfolio w

    is characterized by weights = 36.93%, = 136.93%, = 35.13%, and = 38.74%

    in, respectively, funds w , w , w , and w . Note that the weights of w and w in fund w

    are identical. Furthermore, w s weight in fund w is not only notably larger than w s, it

    is also positive. The intuition for this result is simple. Since w s returns in states s and

    s are positive, a relatively large weight in w is useful to meet the ST constraints. Further

    18

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    21/38

    intuition can be seen in panel (c), which provides the adjustment in expected returns with the

    same effect on the optimal portfolio as the constraints. Observe in line 2 that the expected

    return of all risky securities are notably adjusted downward. Since w is now relatively more

    attractive, the constraints cause the optimal portfolios weight in w to increase substantially.

    The second row of panel (b) shows that w s weights in the risky securities range from

    13.13% (security 1) to 44.52% (security 2). Note that w s weights in securities 1, 3, and 4

    are smaller than those of w , while that in security 2 is larger. The intuition for these results

    is simple. The returns of securities 1, 3, and 4 in states s and s are larger in absolute terms

    than those of security 2. Thus, the ST constraints force a reduction of the weights in securities

    1, 3, and 4. Panel (c) provides further intuition. The largest adjustment in the expected

    return occurs for securities 1 (9.23%), 3 (5.24%), and 4 (3.31%). Consequently, the

    ST constraints lead to a reduction of the weights in these securities. Since security 1 has a

    relatively small adjusted expected return (5.77%), w s weight in this security is negative.

    In contrast, since security 2 has a relatively large adjusted expected return (10.39%), w s

    weight in this security is positive.

    The second row of panel (d) says that w s expected return and standard deviation are,

    respectively, 8.79% and 13.84%. Thus, they are notably smaller than those of w . It can be

    seen that w s returns in states s and s meet the ST constraints. Since w is inefficient,

    of particular interest is its efficiency loss, denoted by , which we measure in terms of

    standard deviation. That is, w s efficiency loss is the increase in standard deviation arising

    from selecting w instead of the efficient portfolio with the same expected return. Note that

    w s efficiency loss is = 3.79%.

    19

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    22/38

    4.3.3. Cost of Stress Testing

    Next, we assess the cost of ST. In doing so, we measure the cost of ST by the reduction

    in the certainty equivalent return incurred by the agent who selects the constrained opti-

    mal portfolio instead of the unconstrained optimal portfolio. Since the certainty equivalent

    returns of the unconstrained and constrained optimal portfolios are, respectively, 10.03%

    and 6.87%, the cost of ST is 3.16%. That is, the protection provided by imposing the ST

    constraints is procured at the cost of a reduction in the certainty equivalent return of 3.16%.

    4.4. Asset Pricing Implications

    Suppose that the constrained agents fraction of the wealth in the economy is = 50%.

    4.4.1. Market Portfolio

    The third row of panel (a) indicates that the market portfolio m is characterized by

    weights = 136.93%, = 17.56%, and = 19.37% in, respectively, funds w , w ,

    and w . The third row of panel (b) shows that ms weights in the risky securities range

    from 14.15% (security 1) to 37.58% (security 2). The third row of panel (d) says that ms

    expected return and standard deviation are, respectively, 12.55% and 18.20%. Thus, they

    are smaller (larger) than those of w (w ). Moreover, ms returns in states s and s are

    smaller (larger) in absolute terms than those of w (w ). Finally, ms efficiency loss is only

    = 0.63%. The reason why we obtain this small efficiency loss is that ms weights in funds

    w and w are substantially smaller than that in fund w .

    4.4.2. Security Expected Returns

    Panel (a) of Table 3 shows the risk premia. First, the CAPMs risk premium is R R =

    8.81%. Second, the risk premium of the idiosyncratic return in state s is = 8.69% so

    20

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    23/38

    that a securitys expected return increases by 8.69 basis points per percentage point of its

    idiosyncratic return in state s . Third, the risk premium of the idiosyncratic return in state

    s is = 7.35% so that a securitys expected return increases by 7.35 basis points per

    percentage point of its idiosyncratic return in state s .

    Panel (b) presents characteristics of the risky securities. The first row shows that their

    betas range from 0.82 (security 4) to 1.22 (security 2). The second and third rows pro-

    vide their idiosyncratic returns in states s and s . While securities 1 and 3 have negative

    idiosyncratic returns in both states, security 2 has positive ones. Security 4 has a negative

    idiosyncratic return in state s , but a positive one in state s .

    Panel (c) decomposes security expected returns in four terms. The first three rows provide

    the two terms contained in the CAPM and their sum, i.e., the CAPM expected return. As

    expected, this sum is higher when the security beta is higher. The next three rows provide

    the two terms that are not present in the CAPM and their sum, i.e., the idiosyncratic return

    adjustment. Since securities 1 and 3 have negative idiosyncratic returns in states s and

    s , the idiosyncratic return adjustment is negative for these securities. The idiosyncratic

    return adjustment for security 1 (2.42%) is larger in absolute terms than that for security

    3 (0.76%) because the idiosyncratic returns of the former are also larger in absolute terms

    than those of the latter as shown in panel (b). Since security 2 has positive idiosyncratic

    returns in states s and s , the idiosyncratic return adjustment for this security is positive

    (1.25%). Finally, since security 4 has a negative idiosyncratic return in state s , but a positive

    one in state s , the idiosyncratic return adjustment for this security is close to zero (0.13%).

    In sum, the idiosyncratic return adjustments can be notably positive or negative.

    21

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    24/38

    5. CONCLUSION

    Over the past ten years, some investors have suffered huge losses due to extreme events

    (e.g., the Barings Bank, LTCM, and Enron failures). In order to prevent such losses, ST

    is now commonly utilized as a risk management tool. For example, the Committee on the

    Global Financial System (2005, pp. 1, 15) of the Bank for International Settlements and

    Scholes (2000) note that ST is often used by banks and securities firms to set risk exposure

    limits. Accordingly, our paper examines a simple model to explore the portfolio selection

    and asset pricing implications of ST constraints.

    Regardless on whether a riskfree security is available, we obtain four main results. First,

    the constrained agents optimal portfolio exhibits (K + 2)-fund separation, where K is the

    number of binding ST constraints. Second, the effect of the constraints on the optimal

    portfolio is identical to that of an adjustment in the expected returns of all risky securities

    that tends to lower them. Hence, the constraints tend to increase the optimal portfolios

    weight in the riskfree security (or the minimum variance portfolio when this security is not

    available). Third, the market portfolio is inefficient. Fourth, a securitys expected return is

    affected by both its systematic risk (i.e., beta) and its idiosyncratic returns in each one of

    those states that are used in the constraints. Specifically, securities with negative (positive)

    idiosyncratic returns in these states have relatively high (low) expected returns in equilibrium.

    Next, we illustrate our theoretical results with a simple example. In this example, there

    are five securities (one of them is riskfree), two agents (each of them has half of the wealth

    in the economy), and two binding ST constraints. Our main findings are as follows. First,

    since there are two constraints, the constrained agents optimal portfolio exhibits four-fund

    separation. Second, the portfolios weights in the two inefficient funds are notable, which

    22

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    25/38

    cause it to have an efficiency loss of 3.79%. Third, since the market portfolios weights in

    these funds are smaller than those of the constrained agents optimal portfolio, the market

    portfolio has an efficiency loss of only 0.63%. Fourth, the effect of the constraints on the

    optimal portfolio is identical to that of a downward adjustment in the expected returns

    of the risky securities ranging from 2.81% to 9.23%. Thus, the weight of the constrained

    agents optimal portfolio in the riskfree security is substantially larger than that of the

    unconstrained agents optimal portfolio. Fifth, the cost of ST as measured by the reduction

    in the certainty equivalent return incurred by selecting the constrained portfolio is 3.16%.

    Finally, the component of a securitys expected return that arises from its idiosyncratic

    returns can be notable. This component is 2.42% for one of the securities that has negative

    idiosyncratic returns in both of the states used in the constraints. However, the component

    is 1.25% for one of the other securities since it has positive idiosyncratic returns in these

    states. In sum, by exploring the implications of ST constraints, we provide further motivation

    to the literature in which security prices are not solely driven by systematic risk.

    23

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    26/38

    APPENDIX

    Proof of Theorem 1. Observe that w solvesmax R +

    w

    (R

    1

    R )

    2w Vw

    . (12)

    A first-order condition for w to solve problem (12) isR 1R Vw = 0. (13)

    Since rank(V) = J, Equation (13) implies that

    w =V (R 1R )

    . (14)

    Using the definition of w and Equation (14), we have Equation (2).

    Proof of Theorem 2. Note that the ST constraints are assumed to bind. Hence, w solvesmax R + w (R 1R )

    2w Vw (15)

    s.t. w (R 1R ) = T R , s = s ,...,s . (16)

    A first-order condition for w to solve problem (15) subject to constraints (16) isR 1R Vw + (R 1R ) = 0, (17)

    where ,..., are Lagrange multipliers associated with these constraints. Since rank(V) =

    J, Equation (17) implies that

    w = V (R 1R ) + V (R 1R ) . (18)Using the definition of w , w ,...,w , and Equation (18), we have Equation (3).

    We now find ,..., . Premultiplying Equation (18) by (R 1R ) and using Equa-

    tion (16), we have

    T R =I +

    I

    , s = s ,...,s , (19)

    24

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    27/38

    where I (R 1R ) V (R 1R ) and I (R 1R ) V (R 1R ). It follows

    from Equation (19) that

    I = [I + (T + R ) ] , s = s ,...,s . (20)Let X [ ] , U [R 1R R 1R ], Y U V U , and

    Z [[I + (T + R ) ] [I + (T + R ) ]] . Using Equation (20), we have

    Y X =Z . Hence, X =Y Z .

    Proof of Theorem 3. The desired result follows from Equations (14) and (18).

    Proof of Theorem 4. We begin by showing that the market portfolio is inefficient. Using

    Equations (2) and (3), we have

    m =

    1

    w + w , (21)

    where

    =

    (1 ) +

    +

    , s = s ,...,s . (22)

    Since (1) = 0 for s = s ,...,s , (2) portfolio w is inefficient for s = s ,...,s , and (3)

    rank([1 R R R ]) = K+ 2, Equation (21) implies that m is also inefficient.

    Next, we show that Equation (5) holds. Using Equation (21) and the definitions of wand

    w , we have

    [ ] = Vm =

    1

    R 1R

    A CR

    +

    R 1R

    F CR

    .

    (23)

    It follows from Equation (23) that

    = m Vm =

    1

    R R

    A CR

    +

    R R

    F CR

    . (24)

    25

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    28/38

    The fact that = and Equations (23) and (24) imply that

    R = R + (R R )

    [(R R ) (R R )]

    1

    A CR

    F CR

    .

    (25)

    Using Equations (22) and (25), we have Equation (5). Note that > 0 since > 0.

    Proof of Theorem 5. Observe that w solves

    max w R

    2w Vw (26)

    s.t. w 1 = 1. (27)

    A first-order condition for w to solve to problem (26) subject to constraint (27) is

    R Vw + 1 = 0, (28)

    where is the Lagrange multiplier associated with this constraint. Since rank(V) = J,

    Equation (28) implies that

    w =V R + V 1

    . (29)

    Using the definition of w and w , and Equation (29), we have Equation (7).

    We now find . Premultiplying Equation (29) by 1 and using constraint (27), we have

    1 = . Hence, = .

    Proof of Theorem 6. Note that the ST constraints are assumed to bind. Hence, w solves

    max w R

    2w Vw (30)

    s.t. w 1 = 1 (31)

    w R = T , s = s ,...,s . (32)

    26

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    29/38

    A first-order condition for w to solve problem (30) subject to constraints (31) and (32) is

    R Vw + 1 +

    R = 0, (33)

    where , ,..., are Lagrange multipliers associated with these constraints. Since rank(V) =

    J, Equation (33) implies that

    w =V R + V 1 +

    V R

    . (34)

    Using the definition of w , w , w ,...,w and Equation (34), we have Equation (8).

    We now find , ,..., . Premultiplying Equation (34) by 1 and using constraint

    (31), we have

    1 =A + C+

    F

    . (35)

    It follows from Equation (35) that

    C+

    F = A. (36)

    Premultiplying Equation (34) by R and using constraint (32), we have

    T =L + F +

    L

    , s = s ,...,s , (37)

    where L R V R and L R V R . It follows from Equation (37) that

    F + L = T L , s = s ,...,s . (38)Let X [ ] , U [1 R R ], Y U V U , and

    Z [ A (T + L ) (T + L )] . Using Equations (36) and (38), we

    have Y X =Z . Hence, X =Y Z .

    Proof of Theorem 7. The desired result follows from Equations (29) and (34).

    27

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    30/38

    Proof of Theorem 8. We begin by showing that the market portfolio m is inefficient.

    Using Equations (7) and (8), we have

    m = 1 w + w + w , (39)where

    = (1 ) + , (40)

    = , s = s ,...,s . (41)

    Since (1) = 0 for s = s ,...,s , (2) portfolio w is inefficient for s = s ,...,s , and (3)

    rank([1 R R R ]) = K+ 2, Equation (39) implies that m is also inefficient.

    Next, we show that Equation (10) holds. Using Equation (39) and the definitions of w ,

    w , and w , we have

    [ ] = Vm =

    1

    1

    C+

    R

    A+

    R

    F. (42)

    It follows from Equation (42) that

    = m Vm =

    1

    1

    C+

    R

    A+

    R

    F. (43)

    The fact that = and Equations (42) and (43) imply that

    R = 1

    A

    C+ R

    1

    A

    C

    R R

    A

    F. (44)

    Using Equations (40), (41), and (44), we have Equation (10). Note that > 0 since

    > 0.

    28

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    31/38

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    32/38

    Francis, J.C., 1978, Portfolio Analysis of Asset and Liability Management in Small-, Medium-and Large-Sized Banks, Journal of Monetary Economics 4, 459480.

    Goyal, A., Santa-Clara, P. 2003, Idiosyncratic Risk Matters!, Journal of Finance 58, 9751007.

    Grossman, S.J., Vila, J.-L., 1992, Optimal Dynamic Trading with Leverage Constraints,Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 27, 151168.

    Grossman, S.J., Zhou, Z., 1993, Optimal Investment Strategies for Controlling Drawdowns,Mathematical Finance 3, 241276.

    Guo, H., Savickas, R., 2006, Idiosyncratic Volatility, Stock Market Volatility, and ExpectedStock Returns, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 24, 4356.

    Hart, O.D., Jaffee, M.D., 1974, On the Application of Portfolio Theory to Depository Finan-cial Intermediaries, Review of Economic Studies 41, 129147.

    Harvey, C.R., Siddique, A., 2000, Conditional Skewness in Asset Pricing Tests, Journal ofFinance 55, 12631295.

    Huang, C., Litzenberger, R.H., 1988, Foundations for Financial Economics, Prentice-Hall,Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

    Hull, J.C., 2006, Options, Futures, & Other Derivatives, Pearson Prentice Hall, Upper SaddleRiver, NJ.

    Jagannathan, R., Korajczyk, R.A., 1986, Assessing the Market Training Performance ofManaged Portfolios, Journal of Business 59, 217235.

    Jorion, P., 2002, How Informative Are Value-at-Risk Disclosures?, Accounting Review 77,911931.

    Kim, D., Santomero, A.M., 1988, Risk in Banking and Capital Regulation, Journal of Fi-nance 43, 12191233.

    Koehn, M., Santomero, A.M., 1980, Regulation of Bank Capital and Portfolio Risk, Journalof Finance 35, 12351244.

    Levy, H., 1978, Equilibrium in an Imperfect Market, American Economic Review 68, 643658.

    Lim, K.-G., 1989, A New Test of the Three-Moment Capital Asset Pricing Model, Journalof Financial and Quantitative Analysis 24, 205216.

    Lintner, J., 1965, The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments inStock Portfolios and Capital Budgets, Review of Economics and Statistics 47, 1337.

    Kraus, A., Litzenberger, R.H. 1976, Skewness Preference and the Valuation of Risk Assets,Journal of Finance 31, 10851100.

    30

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    33/38

    Malkiel, B.G., Xu, Y., 2002, Idiosyncratic Risk and Security Returns, working paper, Uni-versity of Texas at Dallas.

    Malkiel, B.G., Xu, Y., 2003, Investigating the Behavior of Idiosyncratic Volatility, Journalof Business 76, 613644.

    Markowitz, H.M., 1952, Portfolio Selection, Journal of Finance 7, 7791.

    Markowitz, H.M., 1959, Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments, YaleUniversity Press, New Haven, CT.

    Markowitz, H.M., 1987, Mean-Variance Analysis in Portfolio Choice and Capital Markets,Basil Blackwell, New York.

    Markowitz, H.M., van Dijk, E.L., 2003, Single-Period MeanVariance Analysis in a ChangingWorld, Financial Analysts Journal 59, 3044.

    Merton, R.C., 1972, An Analytic Derivation of The Efficient Portfolio Frontier, Journal of

    Financial and Quantitative Analysis 7, 18511872.

    Merton, R.C., 1981, On Market Timing and Investment Performance. I. An EquilibriumTheory of Value for Market Forecasts, Journal of Business 54, 363406.

    Merton, R.C., 1987, A Simple Model of Capital Market Equilibrium with Incomplete Infor-mation, Journal of Finance 42, 483510.

    Mossin, J., 1966, Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market, Econometrica 34, 768783.

    Rochet, J.-C., 1992, Capital Requirements and the Behaviour of Commercial Banks, Euro-pean Economic Review 36, 11371178.

    Roll, R., 1992, A Mean/Variance Analysis of Tracking Error, Journal of Portfolio Manage-ment 18, 13-22.

    Scholes, M.S., 2000, Crisis and Risk Management, American Economic Review 90, 1721.

    Sharpe, W.F., 1964, Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium Under Conditionsof Risk, Journal of Finance 19, 425442.

    Sharpe, W.F., 1987, Asset Allocation Tools, The Scientific Press, Palo Alto, CA.

    Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1997, The Limits of Arbitrage, Journal of Finance 52, 3555.

    31

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    34/38

    Figure 1. Optimal portfolios and the market portfolio in the presence of a

    riskfree security

    This figure illustrates the unconstrained and constrained agents optimal portfolios (w and

    w

    ) and the market portfolio (m

    ), represented by, respectively, points u, c, and m, inthe presence of a riskfree security. Also shown are w , w , w , and w , represented by,

    respectively, points f, t, s , and x. The line represents combinations of w and w (i.e.,

    the efficient frontier). The dashed hyperbola represents combinations ofw and w . The

    dotted line represents combinations ofw and w .

    f

    t

    s

    u

    c

    mx

    R

    1

    32

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    35/38

    Figure 2. Optimal portfolios and the market portfolio in the absence of a

    riskfree security

    This figure illustrates the unconstrained and constrained agents optimal portfolios (w and

    w

    ) and the market portfolio (m

    ), represented by, respectively, points u, c, and m, inthe absence of a riskfree security. Also shown are w , w , w , and w , represented by,

    respectively, points a, b, s , and x. The thick hyperbola represents combinations of w and

    w (i.e., the mean-variance boundary). The dashed hyperbola represents combinations ofw

    and w . The dotted hyperbola represents combinations ofw and w . The thin hyperbola

    represents combinations ofw and w .

    a

    bs

    u

    c

    m

    x

    R

    1

    33

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    36/38

    Table 1. Parameters used in the example

    This table presents the parameters used in the example of Section 6. There are four risky

    securities (j = 1, 2, 3, 4) and a riskfree security (j = 5). Panel (a) shows their annualized

    expected returns (R , j = 1, ..., 5) and standard deviations ( , j = 1, ..., 5). Panel (b) showsthe monthly returns in the states used in stress testing (R and R , j = 1, ..., 5). All

    numbers are reported in percentage terms.

    (a) Annualized expected returns and standard deviations

    j 1 2 3 4 5

    R 15.00 13.20 12.00 10.80 3.74

    27.71 25.98 22.52 20.78 0.00

    (b) Monthly returns in the states used in stress testing

    R 28.00 8.00 11.00 10.00 0.31

    R 29.00 9.00 22.00 10.00 0.31

    34

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    37/38

    Table 2. Optimal portfolios and the market portfolio

    This table presents the unconstrained and constrained agents optimal portfolios (w andw )

    and the market portfolio (m). Panel (a) provides the portfolios fund weights. The weights

    in funds w and w are denoted by, respectively, and . The weights in funds w and

    w are denoted by, respectively, and . Panel (b) provides the portfolios security

    weights. Panel (c) provides the adjustment in expected returns with the same effect on the

    optimal portfolio as the ST constraints and the adjusted expected returns (R , j = 1,..., 4).

    This adjustment depends on the Lagrange multipliers associated with the constraints (

    and ). Panel (d) provides summary statistics on the optimal portfolios and the market

    portfolio. Portfolio ws efficiency loss is denoted by . The rest of the notation is defined

    in Table 1. All numbers are reported in percentage terms.

    (a) Fund weights

    w 36.93 136.93

    w 36.93 136.93 35.13 38.74

    m 136.93 17.56 19.37

    (b) Security weights

    j 1 2 3 4 5

    w

    41.42 30.65 36.36 28.50

    36.93w 13.13 44.52 6.24 25.44 36.93

    m 14.15 37.58 21.30 26.97

    (c) Adjustment in expected returns

    j 1 2 3 4

    R 15.00 13.20 12.00 10.80

    (R R ) + (R R ) 9.23 2.81 5.24 3.31

    R 5.77 10.39 6.76 7.49

    (d) Summary statistics

    j R R R

    w 16.32 25.07 21.02 25.74

    w 8.79 13.84 3.00 4.00 3.79

    m 12.55 18.20 12.01 14.87 0.63

    35

  • 7/31/2019 proiect de tradus

    38/38

    Table 3. Risk premia, security characteristics, and decomposition of

    security expected returns

    Panel (a) provides the risk premia. The risk premia on idiosyncratic returns in states s

    and s are denoted by, respectively, and . Panel (b) presents security characteristics.

    The security betas are denoted by , j = 1, ..., 4. The rest of the notation is defined in

    Tables 1 and 2. Panel (c) decomposes security expected returns. With the exception of the

    idiosyncratic returns in states s and s , all numbers are annualized. With the exception of

    the betas, all numbers are reported in percentage terms.

    (a) Risk premia

    R R 8.81

    8.69

    7.35

    (b) Security characteristics

    j 1 2 3 4

    1.00 1.22 0.85 0.82

    (R R ) (R R ) 15.95 6.66 0.83 0.26

    (R R ) (R R ) 14.08 9.14 9.40 2.07

    (c) Decomposition of security expected returns

    j 1 2 3 4

    R 3.74 3.74 3.74 3.74

    (R R ) 8.84 10.71 7.50 7.19

    CAPM expected return 12.58 14.45 11.24 10.93

    [(R R ) (R R )] 1.39 0.58 0.07 0.02

    [(R R ) (R R )] 1.03 0.67 0.69 0.15

    Idiosyncratic return adjustment

    2.42 1.25

    0.76 0.13

    R 15.00 13.20 12.00 10.80